The Water Page – Water Companies – Urban and Rural

Special Features  Regional trends in project types The previous section looked at the various contract types which private companies enter into with public authorities. These contracts have varying amounts of private and public control over assets and management. Linked with this are the different project types which private companies get involved in. These include:• Management only – the infrastructure is already in place and the private company takes over the operation and management of it for a set period of time. Most common form of contracts – Management, Lease, Service. • Concessions, with investment – operation and management contract for existing infrastructure accompanied by major investments from the private company. Most common form of contracts – BOT, BOO, BOOT, Concession.• Greenfield projects – the private company builds new infrastructure from scratch. Contracts are usually one of the BOT variations.• Divestiture – the private company invests in an equity stake of the utility, either owning it outright or in partnership with other companies or the state. One striking feature of the water and sewerage sector is the dominance of concessions compared with other forms of private participation. Concessions are attractive to governments because they place full operational and investment responsibilities, and associated commercial and investment risk, with the private sector, maximizing potential benefits from efficiency gains and access to private sector financing. DEVELOPING COUNTRIES, BY TYPE OF CONTRACT, 1990–97Developed countries vary in the type of projects and contracts they entered into with private companies to supply water and sanitation services. France typically operates on the system of handing out management contracts to private companies. All the assets and infrastructure are built and owned by the local municipality. Increasingly, concession projects are being entered into, where the private company is responsible for some portion of capital investment in the infrastructure. Germany has started getting more private involvement in water and sanitation through divestitures in state utilities. One of the largest so far is in the Berliner WasserBetriebe, with Vivendi holding 49.9% of the shares and the local government the rest. In this way ultimate control is, theoretically, kept public. Britain is the only country which has gone for 100% divestiture of water and sanitation companies to the private sector. These companies were formed in 1989 and floated on the stock exchange. The USA has public utility corporations which are privately managed but publicly owned. All the assets remain in the public sector. Often private finance, in the form of bonds, is relied upon. There is a trend towards increased private sector involvement and control such as through BOT contracts. The Netherlands also has publicly owned but privately managed water utilities. Privatisation Vs Corporatisation In this model the government is still responsible for the provision of water services, but can raise money on commercial capital markets to do so. Frequently this money is raised through bond issues. This allows members of the public to invest in the utility in order for it to finance capital as well as O&M costs. The problem for developing countries is that, frequently, their local capital markets are not well developed. This makes it difficult for them to raise money through issuing bonds (see box alongside). The result is that governments are forced to either borrow internationally or invite private companies to invest in the utility.Once this happens the situation moves into the realm of PPP of one sort or another. Development assistance from the World Bank is often tied to the condition that services will be privatised. Frequently the result is that countries have little choice, other than to call in private companies. As the private company will be taking on a portion of risk when it makes a capital investment in the water sector, it will want some form of control as security. Depending on the level of investment to be made the company will be granted control over water and sanitation for anything from 2 to 30 years. The extent and duration of the control will be dependent on the contract and project type, as discussed above.Full-scale PPP is the joint ownership of water assets and co-responsibility for the provision of water services. The public and private sector investors can either form a new company or share ownership of an existing one. Under PPP joint ventures, the government remains the ultimate regulator, but it also is an active shareholder in the operating company. From this position, it may share in the operating company’s profits and help ensure the wider political acceptability of its efforts. The private sector partner often has the primary responsibility for performing daily management operations.Joint ventures require that both parties accept the idea of shared risk and shared reward. Each must be willing to make quantifiable contributions throughout the project development and implementation process. Different approaches to financing can be used depending on the nature of the services to be performed – varying from those under service contracts to those resembling concessions. Joint ventures combine the advantages of the private sector – dynamism, access to finance, knowledge of technologies, managerial efficiency, and entrepreneurial sprit –with the social responsibility, environmental awareness, local knowledge, and job generation concerns of the public sector. Under a joint venture, both the public and private sector partners have invested in the company and therefore both have a strong interest in seeing the venture work. This can allow for better conflict management. Full responsibility for investments and operations gives the public and private sector partners a large incentive to make efficient investment decisions and to develop innovative technological solutions, since any gains in efficiency will directly increase their joint returns. Early participation by the public and private sector partners allows for greater innovation and flexibility in project planning and helps ensure that both the public and private partners are able to optimize their goals. Early dialogue between the public and private sector partners can help reduce the transaction costs associated with more traditional tendering processes. Kelantan, Malaysia: State Government Buys Back Privatized Water Supply Thames Water has agreed to sell its entire 70% equity in Kelantan Water for MYR 50 million (EUR 12.4 million) to the Kelantan State Government. Kelantan Water was set up as a joint venture between state agency Yayasan Kelantan Darulnaim (30% equity) and Thames Water (UK) in 1995. Burdened with debts of over MYR 100 million, the company was unable to implement any pipe infrastructure works, bringing housing and commercial projects in the state to a standstill. The people in the state also had to endure low pressure, disruptions and unhygienic water supply. The Prime Minister has offered a MYR 600 million (EUR 149 million) soft loan to the Kelantan government to solve the current water crisis. Source: OECD Report, 2000The government’s continuing regulatory responsibilities may lead to a conflict of interest in maintaining both public accountability and an eye on maximizing returns to the venture. This can increase the risk of political interference and reduce potential gains from private sector management. Private sector organizations tend to focus on the “bottom lineâ€ – governments on the process. These differences are often manifested in the timetables each sector considers reasonable and can create barriers during project development.      Â